DOES THE GREEK BAILOUT PAVE THE WAY FOR THE UNITED STATES OF EUROPE?
The Greek Coup:
Liquidity as a
Weapon of Coercion
Ellen H. Brown: In the modern
global banking system, all banks need a credit line with the central bank in
order to be part of the payments system. Choking off that credit line was a
form of blackmail the Greek government couldn’t refuse.
Former Greek finance minister Yanis
Varoufakis is now being charged with treason for exploring the possibility of
an alternative payment system in the event of a Greek exit from the euro. The
irony of it all was underscored by Raúl Ilargi Meijer, who opined in a July
27th blog:
The fact that these things were
taken into consideration doesn’t mean Syriza was planning a coup . . . . If you
want a coup, look instead at the Troika having wrestled control over Greek
domestic finances. That’s a coup if you ever saw one.
Let’s have an independent
commission look into how on earth it is possible that a cabal of unelected
movers and shakers gets full control over the entire financial structure of a
democratically elected eurozone member government. By all means, let’s see the
legal arguments for this.
So how was that coup pulled off?
The answer seems to be through extortion. The European Central Bank threatened
to turn off the liquidity that all banks – even solvent ones – need to maintain
their day-to-day accounting balances. That threat was made good in the run-up
to the Greek referendum, when the ECB did turn off the liquidity tap and Greek
banks had to close their doors. Businesses were left without supplies and
pensioners without food. How was that apparently criminal act justified? Here
is the rather tortured reasoning of ECB President Mario Draghi at a press
conference on July 16:
There is an article in the
[Maastricht] Treaty that says that basically the ECB has the responsibility to
promote the smooth functioning of the payment system. But this has to do with .
. . the distribution of notes, coins. So not with the provision of liquidity,
which actually is regulated by a different provision, in Article 18.1 in the
ECB Statute: “In order to achieve the objectives of the ESCB [European System of
Central Banks], the ECB and the national central banks may conduct credit
operations with credit institutions and other market participants, with lending
based on adequate collateral.” This is the Treaty provision. But our operations
were not monetary policy operations, but ELA [Emergency Liquidity Assistance]
operations, and so they are regulated by a separate agreement, which makes
explicit reference to the necessity to have sufficient collateral. So, all in
all, liquidity provision has never been unconditional and unlimited. [Emphasis
added.]
In a July 23rd post on Naked
Capitalism, Nathan Tankus calls this “a truly shocking statement.”
Why? Because
all banks rely on their central banks to settle payments with other banks. “If
the smooth functioning of the payments system is defined as the ability of
depository institutions to clear payments,” says Tankus, “the central bank must
ensure that settlement balances are available at some price.”
How the Payments System Works
The role of the central bank in
the payments system is explained by the Bank for International Settlements like
this:
One of the principal functions of
central banks is to be the guardian of public confidence in money, and this
confidence depends crucially on the ability of economic agents to transmit
money and financial instruments smoothly and securely through payment and
settlement systems. . . .
[C]entral banks provide a safe settlement asset and
in most cases they operate systems which allow for the transfer of that
settlement asset.
Internationally before 1971, this
“settlement asset” was gold. Later, it became electronic “settlement balances”
or “reserves” maintained at the central bank. Today, when money travels by
check from Bank A to Bank B, the central bank settles the transfer simply by
adjusting the banks’ respective reserve balances, subtracting from one and
adding to the other.
Checks continue to fly back and
forth all day. If a bank’s reserve account comes up short at the end of the
day, the central bank treats it as an automatic overdraft in the bank’s reserve
account, effectively lending the bank the money in the form of electronic
“liquidity” until the overdraft can be cleared. The bank can cure the deficit
by attracting new deposits or by borrowing from another bank with excess
reserves; and if the whole system is short of reserves, the central bank
creates more to maintain the liquidity of the system.
The most dramatic exercise of
this liquidity function was seen after the banking crisis of 2008, when credit
was frozen and banks had largely stopped lending to each other. The US Federal
Reserve then stepped in and advanced over $16 trillion to financial
institutions through the TAF (Term Asset Facility), the TALF (Term Asset-backed
Securities Loan Facility), and similar facilities, at near-zero interest. Toxic
unmarketable assets were converted into “good collateral” so the banks could
remain solvent and keep their doors open.
Liquidity as a Tool of Coercion
That is how the Fed sees its
role, but the ECB evidently has other ideas about this liquidity tool. Whether
a country’s banks are allowed to “access monetary policy operations” is seen by
the ECB not as mandatory but as discretionary with the central bank. And as a
condition of that access, if a country’s bonds are “below investment grade,”
the country must be under an IMF program — meaning it must subject itself to
forced austerity measures. According to ECB Vice President Constâncio at the
same press conference:
[W]hen a country has a rating
which is below the investment grade which is the minimum, then to access
monetary policy operations, it has to have a waiver. And the waiver is granted
if there are two conditions. The first condition is that the country must be
under a programme with the EU and IMF; and second, we have to assess that there
is credible compliance with such a programme. [Emphasis added]
Liquidity is provided only on
“adequate collateral” — usually government bonds. But whether the bonds are
“adequate” is not determined by their market price. Rather, political
concessions are demanded. The government must sell off public assets, slash
public services, lay off public workers, and subject its fiscal policies to
oversight by unelected bureaucrats who can dictate every line item in the
national budget.
Tankus observes:
Europe now has a system where
liquidity and insolvency problems can occur and can be deliberately generated
(at least in part) by the central bank. Then the Troika can force that country
into an “IMF program” if it wants to continue having a functioning banking
system. Alternatively, the central bank can choose to simply “suspend
convertibility” to the unit of account [i.e. cut off the supply of Euros] and
force the write down of deposits [haircuts and bail-ins] until the banks are
solvent again.
Pushed to the Cliff by the
Financial Mafia
Were liquidity and insolvency
problems intentionally generated in Greece’s case, as Tankus suggests? Let’s
review.
First there was the derivatives
scheme sold to Greece by Goldman Sachs in 2001, which nearly doubled the
nation’s debt by 2005.
Then there was the bank-induced
credit crisis of 2008, when the ECB coerced Greece to bail out its insolvent
private banks, throwing the country itself into bankruptcy.
This was followed in late 2009 by
the intentional overstatement of Greece’s debt by a Eurostat agent who was
later tried criminally for it, triggering the first bailout and accompanying
austerity measures.
The Greek prime minister was
later replaced with an unelected technocrat, former governor of the Bank of
Greece and later vice president of the ECB, who refused a debt restructuring
and instead oversaw a second massive bailout and further austerity measures. An
estimated 90% of the bailout money went right back into the coffers of the
banks.
In December 2014, Goldman Sachs
warned the Greek Parliament that central bank liquidity could be cut off if the
Syriza Party were elected. When it was elected in January, the ECB made good on
the threat, cutting bank liquidity to a trickle.
When Prime Minister Tsipras
called a public referendum in July at which the voters rejected the brutal
austerity being imposed on them, the ECB shuttered the banks.
The Greek government was thus
broken Mafia-style at the knees, until it was forced to abandon its national
sovereignty and watch its public treasures sold off piece by piece. Suspicious
minds might infer that this was a calculated plot designed from the beginning
to throw Greece’s prized assets onto the auction block, a hostile takeover and
asset stripping for the benefit of those well-heeled entities in a position to
purchase them, including the very banks, hedge funds and speculators
instrumental in driving up Greek debt and destroying the economy.
No Sovereignty Without Control
Over Currency and Credit
In the taped conference call for
which Yanis Varoufakis is currently facing treason charges, he exposed the trap
that eurozone countries are now in. It seems there is virtually no legal way to
break free of the euro and the domination of the troika. The government has no
access to the critical data files of its own banks, which are controlled by the
ECB.
Varoufakis said this should alarm
every EU government. As Canadian Prime Minister William Lyon Mackenzie King
warned in 1935:
Once a nation parts with the control
of its currency and credit, it matters not who makes the nation’s laws. Usury, once in control, will wreck any
nation.
For a nation to regain control of
its currency and credit, it needs a central bank with a mandate to serve the
interests of the nation. Banking should be a public utility, serving the
economy and the people.
Ellen H. Brown, Web of Debt
P.S.: “My father made him an
offer he couldn’t refuse. Luca Brasi held a gun to his head and my father
assured him that either his brains, or his signature, would be on the
contract.” — The Godfather (1972)
No comments:
Post a Comment